Many definitions of sustainable
development (often incompatible with each other)have been suggested and debated
in literature. What this suggests is that the debate has exposed a range of
approaches which differ because they are linked to alternative environmental
ideologies. From the ecocentric perspective, the extreme deep ecologists seem
to come close to rejecting even a police of modified development based on the
sustainable use of nature’s assets. For them only minimalist development
strategy is morally supportable. From the opposite technocentric prespective,
other analysts argue that the concept of sustainability contributes little new
to conventional economics theory and policy. Given this worldview, the
maintenance of sustainable economic growth strategy over the long runmerely
depends on the adequacy of investment expenditure. Investment in natural
capital is not irrelevant but is not overriding importance either. A key
assumption of this posisition is that there will continue to be a very high
degree of substitubility between all forms of capital (physical, human, and
nature capital).
The most publicized definition of
sustainability is that of the world commission on environment and development.
The commission defined as development the meets the needs of the present
without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs.
On the basis of this SD definition both
intergenerational equity and intragenerational equity concerns must be met
before any society can attain the goal of sustainability. Social and economic
development must be undertaken in such a way as to minimize the effects of
economic activity (on resource sources and waste assimilation sinks) whenever
the cost are borne by future generations. When currently wital impose cost on
the future. Full compensation must be paid. (performance or assuance bonds
yielding financial aid, or new technologies allowing resource switching say
from fossil fuels to solar power.
The commission also highlighted the
essential needs of the world’s poor, to which overriding priority should be
given. In other words, SD must allow for
an increase in people’s standard of living (broadly definied) with particular
emphasis on the wellbeing of poor people, while at the same time avoiding
uncompensated and significant costs on future people.
The commission also took a fairly
optimistic view of the possibilities for decoupling economic activity and
environmental impact and in terms of our classification system has put itself into the weak
sustainability camp. Recall that the strong sustainability supporters, white
not dismissing decoupling, argue that modifications to the scale of the economy
(the throughput of matter and energy) will also but required, the amount of
scale reduction is debated within the strong sustainability camp.
SD, it is generally agreed, is therefore
economic development that endures over the long run. Economic development can
be measured in terms of gross national product. (the annual output pf goods and
services per capita and imports) per capit, or real consumptions of goods and
services per capita. In a latter section we will argue that, in fact, the traditional GNP measure
needs to be modified and extended if it is to measure SD, but for the moment SD
is definied as at least non-declining consumption, GNP, or some other agreed
welfare indicator.
The conditions for
sustainable development
A more difficult task is to determine the necessary
and sufficient conditions for achieving SD. Fundamentally, how do we compensate
the futurefor damage that our activities today might cause? The answers is
through the transfer of capital bequests. What this means is that this
generation makes sure that it leaves the next generation a stock af capital no
less than this generation has now. Capital provides the capability to generate
wellbeing through the creation of goods and services upon which human wellbeing
depends.
Weak sustainability
(WS)
Under this interpretation of SD, it is not thought
necessary to single out the environment (natural capital) for special
treatment, it is simply another form of capital. Therefore, what is required
for SD is the transfer of an aggregate capital slock no less than the one that
exists now (this then is the weak sustainability constant capital rule). We can
pass on less environment so long as we offset this lose by increasing the stock
of roads and machinery, or other man-made (physical) capital. Alternatively, we
can have fewer roads and factories so long as we compensate by having more
wetlands or mixed woodlands or more education. Perfect substitutability between
the different forms of capital.
Strong Sustainability
(SS)
Under this interpretation of SD, perfect
substitution between different forms of capital is not a valid assumption to
make. Some elements of the natural capital stock cannot be substituted for
(except on a very limited basis) by man-made capital. Some of the function and
services of ecosystems are essential to human survival, they are life support
services (biogeochemical cycling) and cannot be replaced. Other ecological
assets are at least essential to human wellbeing, if not exactly essential for
human survival-landscape, space, and relative peace and quiet. These assets are
critical natural capital and since they are not easily substitutable, if at
all, the SS rule requires that we protect them.
Measuring sustainable
development
Another way of looking at the idea that SD means
generating human wellbeing now without impairing the wellbeing of future
generations is to think about a sustainable flow income. This is a level on
income that the nation can afford to receive without depreciating the overall
capital stock of the nation. The danger is that a failure to adequately account
for natural capital and the contribution it makes to economic welfare and
income will lead to misperceptions about how well an economy is really
performing. This danger is real because the current system of national accounts
used in many countries fails, in almost all cases, to treat natural capital as
assets which play a vital part in providing a flow output/income over time.
Extended national accounts (not restricted to market-based outputs, incomes and
expenditure, as measured in the gross national product concept) are required in
order to improve policy signals relating to SD.
Two adjustments are required, one the depreciation
of natural capital (change in quantity) and the other for degradation if the
natural capital stock (change in quality). A framework to reflect the use of
natural resources at the national level is in the process of being agreed by
the united nations statistical office. However, the theory and practice of
making those adjustments is complex and they are not discussed further here (we
provide some suggested reading at the end of the chapter). Instead we present a
simple test for SD which yields data which is at least indicative of national sustainability. The
test is, however, far from a definitive sustainability indicator, but it is
based on modified national accounting information.
Simple indicator of
sustainable development
One SD rule states that an economy must save at
least as much as the sum of the depreciation on the value of man-made and
natural capital. An analogy with a business is useful in this context. If our
business, to replace machinery and buildings as they wear out (depreciate), we
might stay afloat for a while but not long term-our business would be
unsustainable. The same is true for any economy , its national savings ratio
(savings over some measure of income like gross domestic product (GDP)) must be
greater than or equal to depreciation in the natural capital and man-made
capital stock, if it is to pass our simple sustainability test. Nothing
definitive is being claimed since the data available is not always
comprehensive and the test itself static and ignores factors such as technological change, population growth and
international trade.
Precautionary principle
and safe minimum standards
For some analysts supportive of the strong
sustainability position, sustainability constraints (such as the critical
natural capital protection rule) should be seen as expressions of the so-called
precautionary principle and on similar to the notion of safe minimum standard
(SMS). The SMS concept is one way of giving shape to the intergenerational
social contract idea we discussed. Somehow we have to trade off using resources
to produce economic benefits and conservation of resources stocks and flows to
guarantee sustainable benefit flows. The trade-off decisions have to be taken
within a context of uncertainty and possible irreversibilities (decisions once
taken result in changes that are physically impossible to reverse or
prohibitively expensive to reverse, loss of tropical forests and complex
wetlands). To satisfy the intergenerational social contract (via the constant
capital rule and capital bequests), the current generation could rule out in
advance, depending on the costs (strictly known as the social opportunity
costs, what society has to give up or forgo), development activities that could
result in natural capital depreciation beyond a certain threshold of damage
cost and irreversibility (loss of critical natural capital, life support
service, keystone species and processes). The compatibility between SMS and
strong sustainability is not, however, quite complete. SMS says conserve unless
the benefits forgone are very large. SS says that, whatever the benefits
forgone, loss of critical natural capital is unacceptable.
Sustainable livelihoods
Any sustainable strategy for the future will have to
confront the question of how a much larger total global population can gain
least a basic livelihood in a manner which can be sustained. For the people of
the south, many of their livelihoods will have to endure in environments which
are fragile, marginal and vulnerable. Sustainable livelihoods can only be
promoted via policies which reduce vulnerability. Flood protection to guard
against sea-level rise induced by climate change due to global warming. Measures
to improve food security and offset market and intervention failures such as
inappropriate resource pricing and uncoordinated development policies.
Sustainable
development: operational principles
A number of rules (which fall some way short of a blueprint) for the sustainable utilization of the natural capital stock can now be outlined (roughly ordered to fit the VSS progression):
Market and intervention failures related to resources pricing and property rights should be corrected. Maintenance of the regenerative capacity of renewable natural capital (RNC) harvesting rates should not exceed regeneration rates and avoidance of excessive pollution which could threaten waste assimilation capacities and life support systems.Technological changes should be steered via an indicative planning systems such that, switches from non-renewable (NRNC) to RNC are forested and efficiency-increasing-technical progress should dominate throughput-increasing technology. RNC should be exploited, but at a rate equal to the creation of RNC substitutes (including recycling). The overall scale of economic activity must be limited so that in remains within the carrying capacity of the remaining natural capital. Given the uncertainties present, a precautionary approach should be adopted with a built-in safety margin. Summarizes some of the measure and enabling policy instruments that would be involved in any application of an SD strategy.
Conclusions
Although it has been defined in many
different, and sometimes contradictory, ways the concept of sustainable
development does have both relevance and meaning. Weak and strong versions of
the concept can be distinguished, and a rudimentary measure of sustainability
can be calibrated. How precisely sustainability principles can be translated
into operational practice remains more uncertain. But the framework for general
sustainability rules has been set out and will require adaptation to specific
economic and environmental circumstances.
Tidak ada komentar:
Posting Komentar